The goal of rgamer
is to help students learn Game Theory using R. The functions prepared by the package not only solve basic games such as two-person normal-form games but also provides the users with visual displays that highlight some aspects of the games — payoff matrix, best response correspondence, etc. In addition, it suggests some numerical solutions for games of which it is difficult — or even seems impossible — to derive a closed-form analytical solution.
You can install the development version from GitHub with:
# install.packages("remotes")
remotes::install_github("yukiyanai/rgamer")
or
# install.packages("devtools")
devtools::install_github("yukiyanai/rgamer")
An example of a normal-form game (prisoner’s dilemma).
First, you define the game by normal_form()
:
game1 <- normal_form(
players = c("Kamijo", "Yanai"),
s1 = c("Stays silent", "Betrays"),
s2 = c("Stays silent", "Betrays"),
payoffs1 = c(-1, 0, -3, -2),
payoffs2 = c(-1, -3, 0, -2))
You can specify payoffs for each cell of the game matrix as follows.
game1b <- normal_form(
players = c("Kamijo", "Yanai"),
s1 = c("Stays silent", "Betrays"),
s2 = c("Stays silent", "Betrays"),
cells = list(c(-1, -1), c(-3, 0),
c( 0, -3), c(-2, -2)),
byrow = TRUE)
Then, you can pass it to solve_nfg()
function to get the table of the game and the Nash equilibrium.
s_game1 <- solve_nfg(game1, show_table = FALSE)
#> Pure-strategy NE: [Betrays, Betrays]
s_game1$table
Yanai |
|||
---|---|---|---|
strategy | Stays silent | Betrays | |
Kamijo | Stays silent | -1, -1 | -3, 0^ |
Betrays | 0^, -3 | -2^, -2^ |
An example of a coordination game.
Define the game by normal_form()
:
game2 <- normal_form(
players = c("Kamijo", "Yanai"),
s1 = c("Stag", "Hare"),
s2 = c("Stag", "Hare"),
payoffs1 = c(10, 8, 0, 7),
payoffs2 = c(10, 0, 8, 7))
Then, you can pass it to solve_nfg()
function to get NEs. Set mixed = TRUE
to find mixed-strategy NEs well.
s_game2 <- solve_nfg(game2, mixed = TRUE, show_table = FALSE)
#> Pure-strategy NE: [Stag, Stag], [Hare, Hare]
#> Mixed-strategy NE: [(7/9, 2/9), (7/9, 2/9)]
#> The obtained mixed-strategy NE might be only a part of the solutions.
#> Please examine br_plot (best response plot) carefully.
For a 2-by-2 game, you can plot the best response correspondences as well.
s_game2$br_plot
An example of a normal-form game:
You can define a game by specifying payoff functions as character vectors using normal_form()
:
game3 <- normal_form(
players = c("A", "B"),
payoffs1 = "-x^2 + (28 - y) * x",
payoffs2 = "-y^2 + (28 - x) * y",
par1_lim = c(0, 30),
par2_lim = c(0, 30),
pars = c("x", "y"))
Then, you can pass it to solve_nfg()
, which displays the best response correspondences by default.
s_game3 <- solve_nfg(game3)
#> approximated NE: (9.3, 9.3)
#> The obtained NE might be only a part of the solutions.
#> Please examine br_plot (best response plot) carefully.
An example of a normal-form game:
You can define a normal-form game by specifying payoffs by R functions.
f_x <- function(x, y, a, b) {
-x^a + (b - y) * x
}
f_y <- function(x, y, s, t) {
-y^s + (t - x) * y
}
game4 <- normal_form(
players = c("A", "B"),
payoffs1 = f_x,
payoffs2 = f_y,
par1_lim = c(0, 30),
par2_lim = c(0, 30),
pars = c("x", "y"))
Then, you can approximate a solution numerically by solve_nfg()
. Note that you need to set the parameter values of the function that should be treated as constants by arguments cons1
and cons2
, each of which accepts a named list. In addition, you can suppress the plot of best responses by plot = FALSE
.
s_game4 <- solve_nfg(
game = game4,
cons1 = list(a = 2, b = 28),
cons2 = list(s = 2, t = 28),
plot = FALSE)
#> approximated NE: (9.3, 9.3)
#> The obtained NE might be only a part of the solutions.
#> Please examine br_plot (best response plot) carefully.
You can increase the precision of approximation by precision
, which takes a natural number (default is precision = 1
).
s_game4b <- solve_nfg(
game = game4,
cons1 = list(a = 2, b = 28),
cons2 = list(s = 2, t = 28),
precision = 3)
#> approximated NE: (9.333, 9.333)
#> The obtained NE might be only a part of the solutions.
#> Please examine br_plot (best response plot) carefully.
You can extract the best response plot with NE marked as follows.
s_game4b$br_plot_NE
You can define payoffs by R functions and evaluate them at some discretized values by setting discretize = TRUE
. The following is a Bertrand competition example:
func_price1 <- function(p, q) {
if (p < q) {
profit <- p
} else if (p == q) {
profit <- 0.5 * p
} else {
profit <- 0
}
profit
}
func_price2 <- function(p, q){
if (p > q) {
profit <- q
} else if (p == q) {
profit <- 0.5 * q
} else {
profit <- 0
}
profit
}
game5 <- normal_form(
payoffs1 = func_price1,
payoffs2 = func_price2,
pars = c("p", "q"),
par1_lim = c(0, 10),
par2_lim = c(0, 10),
discretize = TRUE)
Then, you can examine the specified part of the game.
s_game5 <- solve_nfg(game5, mark_br = FALSE)
Player 2 |
|||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
strategy | 0 | 2 | 4 | 6 | 8 | 10 | |
Player 1 | 0 | 0, 0 | 0, 0 | 0, 0 | 0, 0 | 0, 0 | 0, 0 |
2 | 0, 0 | 1, 1 | 2, 0 | 2, 0 | 2, 0 | 2, 0 | |
4 | 0, 0 | 0, 2 | 2, 2 | 4, 0 | 4, 0 | 4, 0 | |
6 | 0, 0 | 0, 2 | 0, 4 | 3, 3 | 6, 0 | 6, 0 | |
8 | 0, 0 | 0, 2 | 0, 4 | 0, 6 | 4, 4 | 8, 0 | |
10 | 0, 0 | 0, 2 | 0, 4 | 0, 6 | 0, 8 | 5, 5 |
You can draw a tree of an extensive form game.
game6 <- extensive_form(
players = list("Yanai",
rep("Kamijo", 2),
rep(NA, 4)),
actions = list(c("stat", "game"),
c("stat", "game"), c("stat", "game")),
payoffs = list(Yanai = c(2, 0, 0, 1),
Kamijo = c(1, 0, 0, 2)),
direction = "right")
And you can find the solution of the game by solve_efg()
.
s_game6 <- solve_efg(game6)
#> backward induction: [(stat), (stat, game)]
Then, you can see the path played under a solution by show_path()
.
show_path(s_game6)